Encyclopedia > Instant Runoff Voting

  Article Content

Instant-runoff voting

Redirected from Instant Runoff Voting

Instant-runoff voting (known as alternative vote or the preferential system in many countries) is a voting system used for elections in single-member districts. It is used, among other places, to elect the House of Representatives in Australia and the president of the Republic of Ireland. It is rarely used in the United States, but in March 2002 it was adopted by voters as the means of electing local candidates in San Francisco. Suggested by Robert's Rules of Order, it is increasingly used in the United States for non-governmental elections, including student elections at Harvard, MIT, Stanford, the Universities of Illinois and Maryland, Vassar and William and Mary.

The system is favored by many third parties, most notably the Green Party, as a solution to the "spoiler" effect third-party sympathizers suffer from under plurality voting (i.e., voters are forced to vote tactically to defeat the candidate they most dislike, rather than for their own preferred candidate). This dilemma rose to national attention most recently in the 2000 election, when supporters of Ralph Nader found themselves caught in a dilemma between voting their conscience or opting for Al Gore in the interests of defeating George W. Bush.

Table of contents
1 External links

Voting

Each voter ranks at least one candidate in order of preference. In most Australian elections, voters are required to rank all candidates.

Counting The Votes

First choices are tallied. If no candidate has the support of a majority of voters, the candidate with the least support is eliminated. A second round of counting takes place, with the votes of supporters of the eliminated candidate now counting for their second choice candidate. After a candidate is eliminated, he or she may not receive any more votes.

This process of counting is repeated until one candidate is the most favored choice of more than fifty percent of voters.

An example

Four candidates: Andrea, Brad, Carter, and Delilah.

12 voters rank the candidates:

  1. Andrea
  2. Brad
  3. Carter
  4. Delilah

8 voters rank the candidates:

  1. Carter
  2. Brad
  3. Delilah
  4. Andrea

4 voters rank the candidates:

  1. Delilah
  2. Brad
  3. Carter
  4. Andrea

1 voter ranked the candidates:

  1. Brad
  2. Carter
  3. Andrea
  4. Delilah

As none of the candidates have reached 50%, the lowest-ranked candidate, Brad, is eliminated. The one voter for him now has his or her ballot count for Carter. The vote table now stands:

  • Andrea: 12
  • Carter: 9
  • Delilah: 4

Delilah is eliminated. The four voters who supported her have their ballots count for the next eligible candidate on their ballots, which turns out to be Carter.

The vote table now stands:

  • Carter: 13
  • Andrea: 12

Carter is elected.

Potential for Tactical Voting

Tactical voting is more difficult under instant runoff preference voting than under plurality voting or standard runoff voting, but easier than under no-preference approval voting. The basic premise of tactical voting within preference voting is to ensure that the proper mix of candidates are left standing toward the end.

For example, suppose there are three candidates: Andrea, Brad, and Carter. It is expected (maybe due to polling) that Andrea will receive 40% of the initial vote, Brad 31%, and Carter 29%. It is also expected that all of Carter's support will prefer Brad to Andrea, whereas half of Brad's support prefer Andrea to Carter. This is not an absurd situation if you say that Andrea is left-of-center, Brad centrist, and Carter right-of-center. In order to attain victory in the final round, some of Andrea's supporters may break off and instead vote Carter first, then Andrea. This would lift Carter to victory over Brad in the first round, after which, Brad's votes - evenly split - lift Andrea to victory in the second round. This scenario is identical to one that may occur in standard runoff voting, assuming that no one would change their vote on a second ballot, as is reasonable for a polarized electorate that votes along 'left-right' lines.

Impact on factions and candidates

Unlike runoff voting, however, there are no chances to deal in between rounds, change voters' minds, or gain support of the other candidates.

Giving them only one chance to do so, instant runoff preference voting encourages candidates to balance earning core support through winning first choice support and earning broad support through winning the second and third preferences of other candidates' core supporters. As with any winner-take-all voting system, however, any bloc of more than half the voters can elect a candidate regardless of the opinion of the rest of the voters.

See also: Runoff voting, Single Transferable Vote, approval voting, Condorcet's method

External links



All Wikipedia text is available under the terms of the GNU Free Documentation License

 
  Search Encyclopedia

Search over one million articles, find something about almost anything!
 
 
  
  Featured Article
Digital Rights Management

...     Contents Digital rights managementRedirected from Digital Rights Management Digital rights management or digital restrictions ...

 
 
 
This page was created in 31.6 ms